Conceptual and Operational Definitions of the Basic Variables Centralization of Power |
||||||||||||||||||
New York: The Free Press and Macmillan, 1980 |
||||||||||||||||||
"CENTRALIZATION OF POWER" as a concept in the analysis of political parties relates to Anderson's dimension of "control" as a concept in organizational theory (1968, pp. 392-396). More specifically, Anderson means the distribution of control instead of the volume or sources of control. In this sense, it is identical with Duverger's concepts of "centralization and decentralization," which Duverger says, "define the way in which power is distributed amongst the different levels of leadership" (1963, p. 52). There is some tendency within the parties literature to confuse "centralization" with "organization," or at least to neglect drawing clear distinctions between the two. Duverger cannot be blamed for this conceptual ambiguity, for he takes pains to distinguish between centralization and articulation (one of our measure of organization). Nevertheless, discussions of party politics frequently equate "strong" party organization with centralization of power.
|
Basic Variable 9.01: Nationalization of Structure [return to top] |
||||||||||||||
Structural arrangements of parties can attach more or less emphasis to national, regional, or local organs in intraparty politics. For example, if no national party organs exist independently of meetings of regional party leaders, there cannot be a basis for centralization of power or effective national direction. Occasionally, parties feature a highly differentiated set of party organs yet leave authority relationships among these organs unspecified, which is conducive to "nationalization" of structure but "decentralization" of power. Variable 8.01, "structural articulation," measures functional differentiation at the national level without regard to hierarchical distribution of power. Variable 9.01 seeks instead to measure hierarchical distribution of power without regard to functional differentiation. The least nationalized structural
arrangements--and thus the most decentralized--occur when
local organizations, commonly at the municipal or county
level, are effectively independent of higher organs. One
government condition that may facilitate this type of local
independence is federalism, although federalism is expected
to have its greatest impact in separating state party organs
from national organs. |
||||||||||||||
Operational Definition. The preceding conceptual considerations are incorporated in this scale. Parties were assigned the lowest applicable code. |
||||||||||||||
|
Basic Variable 9.02: Selecting the National Leader [return to top] |
||||||||||||||||||
At a minimum, a party's "national leader" is the person who acts as the primary spokesman of the party in the country's communications media. At maximum, the national leader may not only fulfill the symbolic function of personifying the party, but he may also be the real locus of power in the party and its effective leader, issuing orders that are regarded as "legitimate" by party members. This variable isolates the set of
procedures used to select the national leader. Selection
procedures reflect processes of negotiation, compromise,
conflict, and cooperation within the party, providing an
indicator of its distribution of power. The most
decentralized or "democratic" method of selection would
involve the direct election of the leader by party members
of even party "identifiers" or supporters. The most
centralized of "oligarchic" method of selection would
involve the leader naming his successor. The range of
alternatives between these points on the continuum might
involve a variety of "open" or "closed" procedures,
including out-and-out skullduggery. In this variable, we are
less interested in the proprieties of the process than in
the numbers and credentials of people who participate in the
selection. |
||||||||||||||||||
Operational Definition. The higher the score on this scale, the more "centralized" is the party on leadership selection. |
||||||||||||||||||
|
Basic Variable 9.03: Selecting Parliamentary Candidates [return to top] |
||||||||||||||||||
Our concern with the distribution of control over the selection of parliamentary candidates stems directly from our definition of parties as "organizations that pursue a goal of placing their avowed representatives in government positions. " The salience of this variable for parties research has been cogently expressed by Schattschneider: The nominating (i.e., candidate selecting) process . . . has become the crucial process of the party. The nature of the nominating procedure determines the nature of the party; he who can make nominations is the owner of the party. It is therefore one of the best points at which to observe the distribution of power within the party," (1942, p. 64). Moreover, according to Ranney, "the candidate selecting process is . . . central to party structure and activity" (1968b, p. 142). Clearly, the selection of candidates offers an important indicator of the centralization of power within the party. For purposes of cross-national comparison, we focus on the selection of parliamentary or legislative candidates. Party candidates for other government positions might have been studied, but no other office or set of offices provides as much opportunity for comparability. For countries which feature a popularly elected chief executive, the preceding variable, "selecting the national leader," often includes party candidates for the top national office. Although the method of selecting
candidates might be conceived in terms of a distinction
between "election" and "designation," we view this as a side
issue and direct our attention instead to the structural
position and functional composition of party organs which
dominate the process, whether one of competitive election or
noncompetitive designation. We are interested in the number
of participants in the decision and their location in the
organizational hierarchy. Hence, the more restricted the
privilege to participate in candidate selection, the more
highly centralized is the party. |
||||||||||||||||||
Operational Definition. The highest applicable value was assigned from this set: |
||||||||||||||||||
|
Basic Variable 9.04: Allocating Funds [return to top] |
||||||||||||||
Regardless of the sources of party funds, a concept embraced in variable 7.01, the levels at which collection and allocation of those funds occur are important in establishing the distribution of power within the party. As Heidenheimer notes, "Crucial to the nature of the support transfer that takes place is who controls the distribution of funds, and whether they are distributed among individual candidates or parties, and if so, on the basis of what criteria" (1963, p. 804). The organizational level that controls the allocation of funds is in a powerful position to set priorities for the attainment of party goals. It is difficult to think of "allocating" funds apart from "collecting" funds, for funds can hardly be allocated unless they are in hand. Collection can occur at different stages, however, with the collection agencies' transferring funds for subsequent allocation by different agencies. In general, we contend that power resides mainly in the agency or level of the party with responsibility for allocating funds obtained either by direct collection or transference of funds collected at another level, although a premium is put on funds collected directly rather than transferred. Recognition must be given also to the
lack of established organizational mechanisms with
responsibilities for collecting and allocating funds. In
some parties, the collection and allocation of funds may be
diffused throughout the entire organization, so that
virtually all levels participate in a helter-skelter
fashion. This lack of structure for allocating funds is
thought to provide for complete decentralization of power,
even more than the situation which obtains when the
collection and allocation of funds are prime
responsibilities of the local organizations. |
||||||||||||||
Operational Definition. This scale incorporates a number of combinations of levels of party organization in the collection and allocation of funds. The higher the level at which the funds are both collected and distributed, the greater the centralization of power in the party. The highest level applicable was recorded. |
||||||||||||||
|
Basic Variable 9.05: Formulating Policy [return to top] |
||||||||||||||||
"The attempt to create and exploit issues of public policy," writes Schattschneider (1942, p. 136), "involves leadership, discipline, and centralization." The information and expertise requisite to cogent policy formation are presumably available principally at the top levels of party hierarchy. Nevertheless, parties differ considerably on the extent to which lower organs participate in policy making. Although there is some doubt about their influence on ultimate party policy, constituency associations within the British Labour Party, for example, continually formulate and press resolutions upon the party at its annual conferences. The program of the Indian National Congress, on the other hand, is determined by a Working Committee dominated by government officials. Numerous personalistic parties constitute the extreme case for the centralization of power in making policy as the party position is expressed--or "revealed," as it were--by the party leader. "Policy" usually suggests the party's
position on substantive issues of government, but "policy"
can also refer to the party's handling of intraparty
affairs, such as campaign strategy. Our main concern in this
variable is to pinpoint the locus of power in determining
the party's position on substantive issues of government.
Our concern is limited to the determination of party policy
and not its implementation in government. |
||||||||||||||||
Operational Definition. A high score on this variable corresponds to the determination and promulgation of policy at elite levels of the organization and is indicative of centralization of power. The lowest applicable score was coded. |
||||||||||||||||
|
Basic Variable 9.06: Controlling Communications [return to top] |
||||||||||||||||
Control of communications or information flow is often cited as a key factor, if not the key factor, in controlling an organization. Undoubtedly, informal conversation is one of the main forms of communication in virtually all organizations, and conversation among party members is difficult to control directly. By skillful use of more formal types of communication, however, a party can often structure the content of conversation indirectly. This leads us to consider the party's access to and control of mass communications media as the major indicator of controlling communications and thereby centralizing power within the organization. Literature distribution (newspapers, magazines, party documents) and electronic broadcasts (radio, television) constitute the two major types of mass communication, with the latter being somewhat more "mass" than the former. Despite the increasing use of electronic broadcasts as a mass communications technique, especially in countries with low literacy rates, the newspaper maintains its position as the main vehicle for party communication. Therefore in considering the control of party communications we look first and foremost at the party press. From the standpoint of centralization
of power, our concern with controlling communications is the
level of the party that controls the content and
distribution of party newspapers (or other form of
communication, if relevant). Apart from the most
decentralized situation which obtains when the party has no
mass communications media of any kind, we regard the control
of party press by local organizations (defined as
constituency/ municipal/county/commune or lower) as a main
condition for decentralization of power. Power is
centralized, however, if the national press is considered to
be "influential" either in the sense of being widely read
across the country by party members and nonmembers alike or
intensively and closely read only by party members. |
||||||||||||||||
Operational Definition. These criteria of (I) existence of facilities for mass communication, (2) the locus of control within the party over publication of information, and (3) the "influence" of the communication are incorporated into the following scale. The higher the score, the greater the degree of centralization. |
||||||||||||||||
|
Basic Variable 9.07: Administering Discipline [return to top] |
||||||||||
t it suggests punishment rather than reward. If we take rewards to mean pleasures, satisfactions, or gratifications that an individual person enjoys, and punishment to refer to other experiences that a person does not enjoy, then the denial of rewards when they are expected can be interpreted as a form of punishment. Our concept of discipline thus includes both rewards and punishments used as inducements to motivate individuals to conform to group behavior. Before considering some typical techniques of discipline, we must identify the class of individuals who are the targets of discipline. Obviously, any party member might be the target of party discipline, but we are interested only in the class of party members who are governmental officials or candidates for governmental office, with particular emphasis on parliamentary or legislative office. We want to determine how the party disciplines the behavior of these members in conformity with group behavior or party principles. In reviewing specific techniques of discipline that are associated with inducing conforming behavior from governmental officials or candidates for governmental office, we restrict ourselves primarily to those that are purely within the party's capability for delivery rather than the government's. For example, rewarding conforming behavior with a government contract may involve the party directly, but this is not purely a party act. On the other hand, expulsion from the party is a disciplinary action that is purely internal to the party. One main reason for drawing this distinction is to control for the additional techniques of discipline in the form of patronage that are available to governing parties but not nongoverning parties. In addition to expulsion from the
party (the most severe form of party discipline--excepting
bodily harm), techniques of discipline can include the
denial of rights normally accorded other members of equal
status, such as participating in party caucuses, receipt of
party communications, access to party resources, and removal
from party office. Although control over nomination for
party candidacy constitutes an important technique of party
discipline, it is not included within this variable
because of its previous inclusion in BV903. All other
techniques of discipline available within a party to
induce conformity on the party of governmental officials and
candidates for government office are included in the
concept. |
||||||||||
Operational Definition. The higher the code, the more centralized the administration of discipline. |
||||||||||
|
Basic Variable 9.08: Leadership Concentration [return to top] |
||||||||||||||
Duverger notes two facts that "have dominated the evolution of political parties since the beginning of the century: the increase in the authority of the leaders and the tendency toward personal forms of authority" (1963, p. 168). In the most extreme situation, "The leader is omniscient, omnipotent, infallible, and infinitely good and wise: every word that falls from his mouth is true; every wish emanating from him is party law" (1963, p. 182). Although it does not necessarily follow that power is more centralized in a party with few leaders rather than many, the fewer the number of individuals involved in party decision making, the more conducive the conditions for centralization of power. "Leadership concentration" refers to
the number of individuals who constitute the top party
hierarchy and who are regarded as key decision makers within
the party. Commonly, these individuals constitute a subgroup
of the party's "executive committee" (see variable 8.01),
which often serves as the effective seat of power in the
organization. But sometimes such committees are only
organizational showcases, which merely legitimate decisions
made by a dominant figure inside or even outside the
committee. This variable aims at effective leadership
concentration, whether formal or informal. |
||||||||||||||
Operational Definition. The following scale incorporates a range of alternative situations in the concentration of leadership, from low to high. For this variable, the exercise of leadership is not to be limited to the electoral stage, which often generates an illusion of leadership concentration as party activists defer to the candidates in the conduct of campaigns. This kind of leader-follower relationship may be short-lived with the resumption of normal political life. |
||||||||||||||
|